Defend Truth

Opinionista

Malikane is wrong, but so are some of his loudest critics

mm

Sean Muller is currently a senior lecturer in economics at the University of Johannesburg, where he teaches microeconomics and industrial policy. Prior to this he worked at the Parliamentary Budget Office and at the University of Cape Town. He has a Master's and PhD in economics from UCT, and an MPhil Economics from Oxford. Among his broad academic interests, within and outside of economics, are a wide range of topics within applied microeconomics, philosophy of economics and public finance. He has been writing opinion pieces on a wide range of South African issues, particularly relating to public policy, for over a decade.

The debate around the new finance minister Malusi Gigaba’s adviser, Chris Malikane, has gone beyond the deeply flawed proposals he has made to claims about his academic credentials and integrity. I want to agree that the proposals are flawed, but that some of the attacks on Malikane are as well. Furthermore, they draw attention to some serious issues in South African academic economics that require mature discussion.

Most of the eight-page “manifesto” published and extensively publicised in various articles and interviews by Chris Malikane is not worthy of serious analysis. It is primarily a political document and contains no substantive content relating to economic policy and public finance. There’s a crude Marxist analysis of class, and a shopping list of things that should be nationalised and services that should be provided. The only interesting assertion is that the working class should throw their weight behind those black South Africans who have become an elite through corrupt government tenders, rather than through credit-based black empowerment schemes.

Like the other assertions, no serious justification is provided. But it certainly explains why Malikane’s radicalism has found favour with Gigaba, whose predecessor appeared to be successfully blocking a range of efforts at tender-related corruption by individuals associated either with the President or the Gupta family. The thinking from Gigaba – a man better known by some for tabloid stories, tailored suits, expensive ties and appearances on Top Billing – may have been that Malikane would provide some solidity to the fig leaf of “radical economic transformation”, while Malikane, who has otherwise been quietly exerting influence in left-wing or trade union movements for some time, clearly thought that his revolutionary moment had arrived.

Some have attempted to defend Malikane on the basis of his academic credentials, to the point of also insisting that his evidently wrong-headed proposals (such as “expropriating banks”) cannot be criticised except through detailed academic analysis. At which point it is useful to invoke a phrase attributed to the Italian computer programmer Alberto Brandolini: “The amount of energy needed to refute bullshit is an order of magnitude bigger than to produce it.” Just because the minister’s adviser has published some academic papers on other subjects does not mean we must presume that his manifesto carries additional weight. Indeed, the primary disappointment for many who had a reasonably high opinion of Malikane up to this point is quite how threadbare his analysis and proposals are.

Where things are getting messy, however, is in attacks on Malikane’s academic credentials. These in fact open up a big can of worms regarding the state of South African academic economics. In fact, one reason I have been delayed in writing a more detailed piece on the notions of radical economic transformation and white monopoly capital, in which Malikane’s manifesto would merit at most a paragraph, is that I had been drafting a conference paper on what “decolonisation of the curriculum” might mean for South African economics.

Understanding Peer Review in Economics

It turns out that the issue of decolonising economics is closely related to some of the misguided aspects of attacks on Malikane. The first, by Stuart Theobald, starts off well enough by noting that Malikane’s published, peer-reviewed work either has relatively little relation to his recent arguments or even – in some cases – seems to contradict those arguments. This is a particularly useful point to make for those who, naively, argue that Malikane’s arguments must be substantive because he has published some academic papers. Where Theobald strays into dangerous territory is in his inferences about Malikane’s integrity and assertions about the wonders of academic peer review.

Theobald’s characterisation of peer review in economics makes me suspect that he has never published anything in the discipline. Very few academics I have come across or read, including Nobel prize winners, have such a rosy view of the peer review process; in practice it is far from the notional ideal of a meritocratic system in which originality and quality are what determine publication. And any problems – of cronyism, bias toward researchers in certain institutions, ideological influences and so forth – are amplified if the basic thrust of your work is critical of, or very different to, the dominant narrative. It does not surprise me that Theobald, given his demographic, his views on economic policy and his area of work (banking and finance), might not be able to appreciate this.

Which brings us to the issue of whether Malikane is dishonest for publishing work with conclusions he does not agree with. My short answer: no. It might be inadvisable, and it is something I personally try to avoid doing (at some cost), but the system is structured in such a way that it can be self-sabotaging to only publish what you believe rather than what you can do. Either you will publish in journals not recognised by your peers, or your career will stall at a junior level, limiting the very time you need for that “against the current” research that is so good it breaks into the mainstream. When co-authors are involved this is even more difficult. This is essentially what Malikane is gesturing at when he says, quoted by Theobald:

Don’t confuse my academic writing and what I believe to be true… you know the business of publishing is so ideologically poisoned that what is published is not necessarily scientific… we sometimes write in order to simply play in the publishing game… not necessarily because we think what we publish is correct… there is heavy ideological repression in academia…

Theobald paints this as sinister and possibly an “act of intellectual dishonesty”. He softens that with a few acknowledgements that Malikane is basically right, but then returns to his gilded age notion of academic publishing. Let me give Theobald the benefit of the doubt and assume he just doesn’t understand how academia works, especially when you are outside the proverbial mainstream.

Finally, Theobald makes the important point that we should not try to judge Malikane the person but rather “whether he has good evidence and reasoning for his claims”. Unfortunately, he then goes completely off the rails by saying that “until [Malikane] publishes them in a way that involves assessment by his peers, we must assume he does not”. Which peers? In what journal? I doubt he would have trouble publishing in the Review of African Political Economy, but similarly doubt Theobald would accept that as adequate. And regardless, I would never accept a policy claim just because someone had managed to publish a paper on it; the idea that successful peer review in economics shows that a claim is “right” is completely wrongheaded, and any economist who advised a minister on that basis should also be fired.

There Are Many Flavours of ‘Bogus Economist’

This usefully brings us to the even more problematic contribution by Co-Pierre Georg. Let me start by saying that I was pleased, albeit surprised, to see – in Georg’s stated concern about “white male patriarchs” – him channelling critiques I myself have made in the past of untransformed gerontocracies and academics behaving like rent seekers. I have, also, for some time been politely raising concerns with various role players about such dynamics at an organisation where Georg has been an associate for some time. I trust he is as vocal on such matters of principle within his institutions, and even when it is personally inconvenient.

The basic assertion of Georg’s article is that people should not trust “bogus economists”. Hard to disagree with, but the devil is in the detail. While writing the above-mentioned draft paper on decolonisation, I made some similar critiques of the quality of the local academic economics to those discussed by Georg. Beyond that, though, we are again in swampy terrain. Georg’s assertion basically translates as: “people should not trust economists I think are bogus, which obviously doesn’t include me, my co-authors, patrons, friends, etc”. It’s not a new trick, including for fake radicals in economics. In a recent comment, an otherwise respected senior scholar in macroeconomics (Paul Romer) published a rather disgraceful attack on various other economists for what he calls “mathiness”. Among these was one of the most famous female economists of the 20th century, Joan Robinson, who by virtue of her gender, left-wing views, and being dead, was an obvious target for Romer. Critiques of excessive or inappropriate use of mathematics in economics are as old as the modern version of the discipline itself. But a close reading of Romer’s critique reveals a petty, self-serving definition of the crime: when economists he doesn’t like use mathematics, they are guilty of “mathiness”, whereas when economists he does like (obviously including himself) use mathematics then it’s done properly. Georg’s argument boils down to a similarly crude skeleton. (Romer, incidentally, was then appointed chief economist at the World Bank – illustrating how dysfunctional economics can be in other places).

Furthermore, Georg peddles a version of how economics can inform policy that is popular with certain types of academic economists, but bares little relation to reality. In this model, people who can write the most complex mathematical equations, estimate the most complex econometric models and get published in high-ranked journals are best positioned to advise on policy. It would be funny if it weren’t so tragic and, in its own way, dangerous. There are some individuals who have managed to make the transition, but it is the exception rather than the norm. The last thing a finance minister needs is some social incompetent who thinks he can figure out a policy solution by writing down an equation, running a model or looking for a “peer-reviewed solution’”. If you need an academic perspective, your adviser talks to a deputy director general who gets someone in the research cluster to do it, or outsources it to an academic like Georg.

Yet Georg does not hold back, offering to define for us what a “proper academic” is. But the best he can do in this regard, like Theobald, is to refer to “peer review”. I have already made clear that this is a naïve, and in Georg’s case arguably self-serving, use of the notion of peer review. Again, one can tell that Georg is not exactly familiar with the challenges of swimming against the current. Or, in fact, advising on broad economic policy in the complex South African terrain.

A Necessary Debate

In some ways, the great tragedy of the Malikane saga is that, in principle, he should have been in a position to be a very good adviser – albeit one with strong left-wing views. While the likes of Theobald and Georg might be good advisers at lower levels of the hierarchy on specific issues relating to banking and finance, I certainly think Malikane’s broad credentials should have made him a better choice for a general adviser to a minister. Given that, fortunately, it looks like his manifesto will have no impact whatsoever – with various politicians suddenly realising that talking up radical economic transformation is a bad idea if it means emptying the fiscus you had planned on looting – the most harm done is to Malikane himself. But he has also damaged the possibility of more open discussions about economic and fiscal policy, which means that in fact those who should be most angry with him are economists (including myself) who believe such a conversation is sorely needed.

The bigger picture that Theobald and Georg’s misplaced attacks draw attention to is the state of South African academic economics. Some time ago as a student I witnessed the destructive consequences of the failure by some otherwise very respectable, academics to reconcile tensions within the local discipline. The result, I think, has been for many to bury their heads in the sand and hope for the best. Or, less innocently, to set up fiefdoms in which they can propagate their own views and agendas without the inconvenience of differing views.

To be fair, similar behaviour is happening in a range of other South African academic disciplines. However, besides the fact that this is an unhealthy state of affairs, legitimate calls for transformation and decolonisation (appropriately defined) will only ratchet up these tensions and it would be best to address them openly and as maturely as we can. The position I have come to is in some ways rather obvious: we need to raise standards, but we also need a wide diversity of views and therefore should be pluralist in our approach to defining who is a competent economist (academic or otherwise). In that context, we would be advised to avoid doing things like accusing a fellow academic of not being a “proper economist” or being “intellectually dishonest”, when they have a PhD from a very reputable North American institution, some competent publications, and extensive engagement in and knowledge of South African civil society. Other people may have their own basis for arguing that you are not a “proper economist” for their purposes, and those are surely not the kind of dynamics we want to encourage. DM

Gallery

Please peer review 3 community comments before your comment can be posted

Become a Maverick Insider

This could have been a paywall

On another site this would have been a paywall. Maverick Insider keeps our content free for all.

Become an Insider

Every seed of hope will one day sprout.

South African citizens throughout the country are standing up for our human rights. Stay informed, connected and inspired by our weekly FREE Maverick Citizen newsletter.